Side-by-side Chinese-English

组织成本、专有性资源与农村资金互助社发起人控制

朱乾宇1 罗兴1 马九杰1

(1.中国人民大学农业与农村发展学院)

【摘要】本文基于组织成本和专有性资源理论,运用博弈论及案例分析方法,对成立初期的农村资金互助社的发起人控制现象进行了分析和验证。本文的主要结论为:发起人投入的组织成本和专有性资源在农村资金互助社的发起成立和运行中发挥了重要作用,但也使发起人显著异质于普通社员而处于强谈判地位。在没有外部干预的情况下,发起人倾向于占有合作组织的剩余索取权和剩余控制权;当农村资金互助社遇到外部干预时,在软约束情况下仍会出现发起人控制现象,而硬约束会逼迫发起人选择解体合作组织或转变为道德高尚者。

【关键词】 农村资金互助社;发起人控制;组织成本;专有性资源;

【DOI】

【基金资助】 中国人民大学预研委托项目之团队培育计划项目“城乡间资金流动、普惠金融创新与城乡发展一体化研究”(编号:14XNQ017)的资助;

The organizational cost, exclusive resources and the initiator’s control of the rural mutual financial cooperative

ZHU Qianyu1 LUO Xing1 MA Jiujie1

(1.School of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development, Renmin University of China)

【Abstract】This paper, based on theories of the organizational cost and exclusive resources, adopted the game theory and the method of case analysis to analyze and verify the initiator’s control of the RMFC at its beginning. According to its main conclusion, the organizational cost and exclusive resources put in by the initiators played an important role in the initiation and operation of the RMFC, which provided the initiators with a strong bargaining position, significantly heterogeneous to the common members. Without external intervention, the initiators tended to possess the residual claim and residual rights of control of the RMFC. When the RMFC meet external intervention, the initiators could still have control under soft restraints while chose to dissolve the organization or turned to moral persons under hard restraints.

【Keywords】 the rural mutual financial cooperative; the initiator’s control; the organizational cost; exclusive resources;

【DOI】

【Funds】 Supported by the plan to build teams of the entrusted pre-research project of Renmin University of China (14XNQ017);

Download this article
    Footnote

    [1]. (1) Now, China’s mutual financial cooperative adopts the system of initiators for initiation. It requires at least ten initiators in line with the regulations to initiate and establish a mutual financial cooperative. Therefore, in reality, the phenomenon that a group of over ten initiators initiate and dominate the RMFC exists. [^Back]

    [2]. (1) The exclusive concept came from the study of Yang Ruilong and Yang Qijing (2001) about the system of enterprises. They believed that the system arrangement of enterprises is not the product of minimizing the transaction cost but the game result of the rational participants according to their specific assets rather than specific assets. Exclusive assets are different from specific assets for their emphasis on the exclusiveness of assets and their importance to team production. [^Back]

    [3]. (1) Common members are common farmers before joining the RMFC. Common members and common farmers are the same group. However, the analysis of this paper starts from before the initiation of the RMFC, so the group is called as common farmers before such initiation in the following sections, especially in the part of theoretical analysis. [^Back]

    [4]. (2) The above resources are not necessary to focus on one person. Some member from the group of initiators may have one kind or many kinds of resources. [^Back]

    [5]. (1) After the RMFC works with good performance, many farmers want to participate in the distribution of organizational surplus as shareholders, but the initiators generally disapprove, for the funds are not exclusive resources at the moment. [^Back]

    [6]. (1) This paper does not deny the existence of moral persons in the rural area. Initiating the RMFC, the moral persons take consideration of not only financial benefits but also spiritual benefits such as honour, respect from the community members. However, the moral persons are not common, so this paper takes no consideration of the moral persons when building the model of ex-ante game. [^Back]

    [7]. (2) The Interim Provisions on the Administration of Rural Mutual Cooperatives have no clear requirement on the distributing method of the surplus of the RMFC. However, the Law of the People's Republic of China on Specialized Farmers Cooperatives promulgated in 2006 and the Opinions on Guiding and Promoting the Standardized Development of Specialized Farmers' Cooperatives issued by the nine ministries/commissions, including the Ministry of Agriculture of the People's Republic of China and the National Development and Reform Commission in August, 2014, had clear regulations on distributing the surplus of cooperatives. In other words, the distributable surplus returned according to the proportion of the trading volume (amount) of the members to that of the cooperative should not be lower than 60% of the total distributable surplus. [^Back]

    [8]. (1) The RMFC, restrained by the social network of acquaintances (without cross-regional operation), generally have a limited size and organizational profits. Some cooperative organizations can expand by sharing organizational profits (i.e. by lowering the proportion of profits got by the main initiator) to raise profits of the organization and finally the profits of the main initiator. [^Back]

    [9]. (2) It is because S (a) > (1 - a) R (a) to common farmers, (1 - a) R (a) + S (a) is the increasing function of a. In other words, the higher a is, the higher profits common farmers receive. [^Back]

    [10]. (3) LM Fishing Cooperative had 46 members at the beginning. The capital of CNY 1000 per household was deposited in AJ Cooperative as original issue stocks for dividends. Later, the capital owned by over 30 members which was also deposited in AJ Cooperative did not participate in the distribution of dividends, but just as common shares of the members. [^Back]

    References

    [1] Chen, D. & Zhou, Z. Jiangsu Social Sciences (江苏社会科学), (2) (2012).

    [2] Chen, D. & Ren, P. Journal of Nanjing Agricultural University (Social Sciences Edition) (南京农业大学学报 (社会科学版)), (4) (2013).

    [3] Cheng, S. China’s Rural Development: theory and practice (中国农村发展: 理论和实践). Beijing: China Renmin University Press, (1999).

    [4] Dong, X., Xu, H. and Yi, J. Chinese Rural Economy (中国农村经济), (10) (2012).

    [5] Guan, Y. Northern Financial Research (内蒙古金融研究), (9) (2008).

    [6] Huang, J. & Zhu, G. Journal of Agrotechnical Economics (农业技术经济), (5) (2007).

    [7] Huang, S. & Xu, X. Journal of Nanjing Agricultural University (Social Sciences Edition) (南京农业大学学报 (社会科学版)), (3) (2008).

    [8] Kong, X. & Jiang, C. Rural Economy (农村经济),(9) (2010).

    [9] Li, C. & Zhang, X. Rural Economy and Science-Technology (农村经济与科技), (3) (2008).

    [10] Ma, J. & Zhou, X. Jianghan Tribune (江汉论坛), (5) (2013).

    [11] [Japan] Aoki, M. The Co-operative Game Theory Of The Firm (企业的合作博弈理论). Zheng, J. (trans.). Beijing: China Renmin University Press, (2004).

    [12] Wen, T. Economic Theory and Business Management (经济理论与经济管理), (7) (2009).

    [13] Wen, T. & Yang, S. Theoretical Investigation (理论探讨), (6) (2012).

    [14] Xu, H., Wang, K. & Li, H. Shandong Economy (山东经济), (3) (2010).

    [15] Yang, R. & Yang, Q. Economic Research Journal (经济研究), (3) (2001).

    [16] Zhou, Q. Economic Research Journal (经济研究), (6) (1996).

    [17] Zhou, L. Economy Survey (经济经纬), (6) (2006).

    [18] Zhou, Y. & Wang, A. Finance and Trade Research (财贸研究), (2) (2013).

    [19] Alchian, A. & Demsetz, H.: Production, Information Costs and Economic Organization, American Economic Review, 62 (5): 777–795, 1972.

    [20] Alchian, A. & Woodward, S.: Reflection on the Theory of the Firm, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 143 (1): 110–136, 1987.

    [21] Fritzen, S. A.: Can the Design of Community-driven Development Reduce the Risk of Elite? Capture Evidence from Indonesia, World Development, 35 (8): 1359–1375, 2007.

This Article

ISSN:1002-8870

CN: 11-1262/F

Vol , No. 12, Pages 49-62

December 2015

Downloads:6

Share
Article Outline

Abstract

  • 1 Introduction
  • 2 The theoretical framework and the research hypothesis
  • 3 The case study
  • 4 Conclusion and policy implications
  • Footnote

    References